Yuri Ostrovsky
Martin Munk
Anton Heil
Maitreesh Ghatak
Robin Burgess
Oriana Bandiera
Claire Balboni
Jonna Olsson
Richard Foltyn
Minjie Deng
Iiyana Kuziemko
Elisa Jácome
Juan Pablo Rud
Bridget Hofmann
Sumaiya Rahman
Martin Nybom
Stephen Machin
Hans van Kippersluis
Anne C. Gielen
Espen Bratberg
Jo Blanden
Adrian Adermon
Maximilian Hell
Robert Manduca
Robert Manduca
Marta Morazzoni
Aadesh Gupta
David Wengrow
Damian Phelan
Amanda Dahlstrand
Andrea Guariso
Erika Deserranno
Lukas Hensel
Stefano Caria
Vrinda Mittal
Ararat Gocmen
Clara Martínez-Toledano
Yves Steinebach
Breno Sampaio
Joana Naritomi
Diogo Britto
François Gerard
Filippo Pallotti
Heather Sarsons
Kristóf Madarász
Anna Becker
Lucas Conwell
Michela Carlana
Katja Seim
Joao Granja
Jason Sockin
Todd Schoellman
Paolo Martellini
UCL Policy Lab
Natalia Ramondo
Javier Cravino
Vanessa Alviarez
Hugo Reis
Pedro Carneiro
Raul Santaeulalia-Llopis
Diego Restuccia
Chaoran Chen
Brad J. Hershbein
Claudia Macaluso
Chen Yeh
Xuan Tam
Xin Tang
Marina M. Tavares
Adrian Peralta-Alva
Carlos Carillo-Tudela
Felix Koenig
Joze Sambt
Ronald Lee
James Sefton
David McCarthy
Bledi Taska
Carter Braxton
Alp Simsek
Plamen T. Nenov
Gabriel Chodorow-Reich
Virgiliu Midrigan
Corina Boar
Sauro Mocetti
Guglielmo Barone
Steven J. Davis
Nicholas Bloom
José María Barrero
Thomas Sampson
Adrien Matray
Natalie Bau
Darryl Koehler
Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Alan J. Auerbach
Irina Popova
Alexander Ludwig
Dirk Krueger
Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln
Taylor Jaworski
Walker Hanlon
Ludo Visschers
Angus Foulis
Saleem Bahaj
Stone Centre at UCL
Phil Thornton
James Baggaley
Xavier Jaravel
Richard Blundell
Parama Chaudhury
Dani Rodrik
Alan Olivi
Vincent Sterk
Davide Melcangi
Enrico Miglino
Fabian Kosse
Daniel Wilhelm
Azeem M. Shaikh
Joseph Romano
Magne Mogstad
Suresh Naidu
Ilyana Kuziemko
Daniel Herbst
Henry Farber
Lisa Windsteiger
Ruben Durante
Mathias Dolls
Cevat Giray Aksoy
Angel Sánchez
Penélope Hernández
Antonio Cabrales
Wendy Carlin
Suphanit Piyapromdee
Garud Iyengar
Willemien Kets
Rajiv Sethi
Ralph Luetticke
Benjamin Born
Amy Bogaard
Mattia Fochesato
Samuel Bowles
Guanyi Wang
CORE Econ
David Cai
Toru Kitagawa
Michela Tincani
Christian Bayer
Arun Advani
Elliott Ash
Imran Rasul

Subjective life expectancies, time preference heterogeneity, and wealth inequality

What is this research about and why did you do it?

This paper examines how objective and subjective heterogeneity in life expectancy affects savings behavior of healthy and unhealthy people. Standard consumption/savings theory predicts that people who place a larger weight on future states will be wealthier than people who are more impatient, all else equal. We asked ourselves: how much of the observed health-wealth gap can be explained by the fact that unhealthy individuals expect to live a shorter time, thus put a smaller weight on future states, and are therefore not willing to save as much?

How did you answer this question?

Using data from the Health and Retirement Study, we first investigated what individuals actually think about their probability of surviving to older ages, and then compared those beliefs to a statistical measure of their life expectancy, conditional on a rich set of covariates. To gauge the effect of the subjective beliefs on savings behavior and wealth accumulation, we used an overlapping-generations model where survival probabilities and beliefs evolve according to a health and survival process estimated to capture the elicited beliefs from the data.  

What did you find?

First, we found systematic biases in survival beliefs across self-reported health: those in poor health not only have a shorter actual lifespan but also underestimate their remaining life time. Second, using the structural OLG model, we were able to quantify the importance of these belief biases for wealth accumulation. We concluded that differences in life expectancy are important to understand savings behavior, and that the belief biases, especially among the unhealthy, can explain up to a fifth of the observed health-wealth gap.

Elicited beliefs about survival versus estimated objective (statistical) survival probabilities for nonblack men. Each bubble represents the average for an age/health group. The x-axis shows the model-predicted (objective) survival probability to the age of 75. The y-axis shows the average self-reported survival probability for that group and age. Colors indicate the health state: dark green is excellent while red is poor health. The size indicates the number of observations in each cell.

What implications does this have for the study (research and teaching) of wealth concentration or economic inequality?

This paper ties into a strand of current research investigating preference heterogeneity and its importance for individual choices and aggregate outcomes. We provide an intuitively plausible and micro-founded source of heterogeneity: the perceived probability of surviving to future states of the world. Our quantification of this channel shows that life expectancy heterogeneity is important and should be included in the list of potential sources of heterogeneity that we need to consider in our analyses.

What are the next steps in your agenda?

We continue to investigate how life expectancy heterogeneity shape economic outcomes, in particular how this heterogeneity contribute to wealth inequality. For instance, how does life expectancy inequality contribute to differences in retirement wealth?

Citation and related resources

Foltyn, R. and Olsson, J. Subjective life expectancies, time preference heterogeneity, and wealth inequality. Quantitative Economics 15, no. 3(2024): 699-736.

About the authors