Aadesh Gupta
David Wengrow
Damian Phelan
Amanda Dahlstrand
Andrea Guariso
Erika Deserranno
Lukas Hensel
Stefano Caria
Vrinda Mittal
Ararat Gocmen
Clara Martínez-Toledano
Yves Steinebach
Breno Sampaio
Joana Naritomi
Diogo Britto
François Gerard
Filippo Pallotti
Heather Sarsons
Kristóf Madarász
Anna Becker
Lucas Conwell
Michela Carlana
Katja Seim
Joao Granja
Jason Sockin
Todd Schoellman
Paolo Martellini
UCL Policy Lab
Natalia Ramondo
Javier Cravino
Vanessa Alviarez
Hugo Reis
Pedro Carneiro
Raul Santaeulalia-Llopis
Diego Restuccia
Chaoran Chen
Brad J. Hershbein
Claudia Macaluso
Chen Yeh
Xuan Tam
Xin Tang
Marina M. Tavares
Adrian Peralta-Alva
Carlos Carillo-Tudela
Felix Koenig
Joze Sambt
Ronald Lee
James Sefton
David McCarthy
Bledi Taska
Carter Braxton
Alp Simsek
Plamen T. Nenov
Gabriel Chodorow-Reich
Virgiliu Midrigan
Corina Boar
Sauro Mocetti
Guglielmo Barone
Steven J. Davis
Nicholas Bloom
José María Barrero
Thomas Sampson
Adrien Matray
Natalie Bau
Darryl Koehler
Laurence J. Kotlikoff
Alan J. Auerbach
Irina Popova
Alexander Ludwig
Dirk Krueger
Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln
Taylor Jaworski
Walker Hanlon
Ludo Visschers
Henrik Kleven
Kristian Jakobsen
Katrine Marie Jakobsen
Alessandro Guarnieri
Tanguy van Ypersele
Fabien Petit
Cecilia García-Peñalosa
Yonatan Berman
Nina Weber
Julian Limberg
David Hope
Pedro Tremacoldi-Rossi
Tatiana Mocanu
Marco Ranaldi
Silvia Vannutelli
Raymond Fisman
John Voorheis
Reed Walker
Janet Currie
Roel Dom
Marcos Vera-Hernández
Emla Fitzsimons
José V. Rodríguez Mora
Tomasa Rodrigo
Álvaro Ortiz
Stephen Hansen
Vasco Carvalho
Gergely Buda
Gabriel Zucman
Anders Jensen
Matthew Fisher-Post
José-Alberto Guerra
Myra Mohnen
Christopher Timmins
Ignacio Sarmiento-Barbieri
Peter Christensen
Linda Wu
Gaurav Khatri
Julián Costas-Fernández
Eleonora Patacchini
Jorgen Harris
Marco Battaglini
Ricardo Fernholz
Alberto Bisin
Jess Benhabib
Cian Ruane
Pete Klenow
Mark Bils
Peter Hull
Will Dobbie
David Arnold
Eric Zwick
Owen Zidar
Matt Smith
Ansgar Walther
Tarun Ramadorai
Paul Goldsmith-Pinkham
Andreas Fuster
Ellora Derenoncourt
Golvine de Rochambeau
Vinayak Iyer
Jonas Hjort
Elena Simintzi
Paige Ouimet
Holger Mueller
Pablo Garriga
Gabriel Ulyssea
Costas Meghir
Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg
Rafael Dix-Carneiro
Alessandro Toppeta
Áureo de Paula
Orazio Attanasio
Seth Zimmerman
Joseph Price
Valerie Michelman
Camille Semelet
Anne Brockmeyer
Pierre Bachas
Santiago Pérez
Elisa Jácome
Leah Boustan
Ran Abramitzky
Jesse Rothstein
Jeffrey T. Denning
Sandra Black
Wei Cui
Mathieu Leduc
Philippe Jehiel
Shivam Gujral
Suraj Sridhar
Attila Lindner
Arindrajit Dube
Pascual Restrepo
Łukasz Rachel
Benjamin Moll
Kirill Borusyak
Michael McMahon
Frederic Malherbe
Gabor Pinter
Angus Foulis
Saleem Bahaj
Stone Centre
Phil Thornton
James Baggaley
Xavier Jaravel
Richard Blundell
Parama Chaudhury
Dani Rodrik
Alan Olivi
Vincent Sterk
Davide Melcangi
Enrico Miglino
Fabian Kosse
Daniel Wilhelm
Azeem M. Shaikh
Joseph Romano
Magne Mogstad
Suresh Naidu
Ilyana Kuziemko
Daniel Herbst
Henry Farber
Lisa Windsteiger
Ruben Durante
Mathias Dolls
Cevat Giray Aksoy

Land misallocation and productivity

What is this research about and why did you do it?

A fundamental question in the field of economic growth and development is why some countries are rich and others poor. Existing literature has reached a consensus that cross-country differences in labour productivity are substantially larger in agriculture than in the non-agricultural sectors. Moreover, factor misallocation among heterogeneous producers is important in accounting for cross-country productivity differences. This paper builds on these two perspectives. Specifically, we use micro-level panel data from Malawi to assess the extent of factor misallocation in agriculture, aiming to shed new light on how resource misallocation contributes to the low agricultural and aggregate productivity observed in low-income countries.

How did you answer this question?

We start by estimating farm-level productivity using panel data, controlling for transitory variation, and minimizing potential measurement error. We then construct a framework with the only imposed structure being the span of control of heterogeneous farmers and hence the equilibrium farm-size distribution is non-degenerate. This framework serves as a lens through which we evaluate the data, drawing a comparison between the actual allocation of resources and the model's implied efficient allocation. We also quantify the aggregate productivity gain achievable by reallocating resources to their efficient allocation and compare the impact on inequality among farmers between the actual and the efficient allocations.

What did you find?

Capital and land inputs are substantially misallocated. Specifically, the efficient allocation implies that more productive farmers should operate larger farms, while actual capital and land inputs in the data are largely uncorrelated with farm productivity. Redirecting capital and land from less productive farms to more productive farms to equate their marginal products increases aggregate output by 1.7—2.0 folds, holding quantities of aggregate inputs unchanged. This gain is substantial even if we restrict the reallocation to be within narrowly defined geographic areas. Moreover, evidence suggests that land rental markets alleviate resource misallocation.

Figure notes: Each (blue) dot represents a household farm in the data whereas the (red) dashed line represents the efficient allocation. All variables have been logged. The efficient allocation implies that more productive farmers should operate larger farms, while actual capital and land inputs in the data are largely uncorrelated with farm productivity.

What implications does this have for the study (research and teaching) of wealth concentration or economic inequality?

Inequality among farmers is always a concern of land reallocation. We find that the model-implied efficient allocation, despite concentrated land usage, reduces inequality among farmers and poverty compared to the actual allocation. The key is that low-productivity farmers, which are also low income, benefit more from land rental income than the farming revenue associated with operating their own land. This result highlights the possibility of improving productivity without exacerbating inequality by allowing for rentals (usership) while maintaining land ownership.

What are the next steps in your agenda?

In companion projects, we investigate how land rentals causally reduce resource misallocation, exploring exogenous variations across space and time arising from a decentralized land reform in Ethiopia. We also assess how land insecurity in China affects rural-urban migration and inequality.

Citation

Chaoran, C., Restuccia, D., and Santaeulalia-Llopis, R. 2023. “Land Misallocation and Productivity.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 15(2), pp 441-65.

About the authors